Benkler on network topology and its implications for democracy (From Chapter Seven, section 5 of The Wealth of Networks)

 

Developments in network topology theory and its relationship to the structure of the empirically mapped real Internet offer a map of the networked information environment that is indeed quite different from the naïve model of "everyone a pamphleteer."

First, links are not smoothly distributed throughout the network.

Second, at a macrolevel and in smaller subclusters, the power law distribution does not resolve into everyone being connected in a mass-media model relationship to a small number of major "backbone" sites.

figure 7.5

Figure 7.5: Bow Tie Structure of the Web

One way of interpreting this structure as counterdemocratic is to say: This means that half of all Web sites are not reachable from the other half - the "IN," "tendrils," and disconnected portions cannot be reached from any of the sites in SCC and OUT.

Third, another finding of Web topology and critical adjustment to the basic Barabási and Albert model is that when the topically or organizationally related clusters become small enough - on the order of hundreds or even low thousands of Web pages - they no longer follow a pure power law distribution.

figure 7.6

Figure 7.6: Illustration of a Skew Distribution That Does Not Follow a Power Law

These findings are critical to the interpretation of the distribution of links as it relates to human attention and communication.

The fourth and last piece of mapping the network as a platform for the public sphere is called the "small-worlds effect."

Based on Stanley Milgram's sociological experiment and on mathematical models later proposed by Duncan Watts and Steven Strogatz, both theoretical and empirical work has shown that the number of links that must be traversed from any point in the network to any other point is relatively small./28

Fairly shallow "walks" - that is, clicking through three or four layers of links - allow a user to cover a large portion of the Web.

What is true of the Web as a whole turns out to be true of the blogosphere as well, and even of the specifically political blogosphere.

This body of literature on network topology suggests a model for how order has emerged on the Internet, the World Wide Web, and the blogosphere.

Individuals and individual organizations cluster around topical, organizational, or other common features.

The result is an ordered system of intake, filtering, and synthesis that can in theory emerge in networks generally, and empirically has been shown to have emerged on the Web.

The effects of the topology of the network are reinforced by the cultural forms of linking, e-mail lists, and the writable Web.

Our understanding of the emerging structure of the networked information environment, then, provides the basis for a response to the family of criticisms of the first generation claims that the Internet democratizes.

The second claim was that fragmentation would cause polarization.

The third claim was that money would reemerge as the primary source of power brokerage because of the difficulty of getting attention on the Net.

The peer-produced structure of the attention backbone suggests that money is neither necessary nor sufficient to attract attention in the networked public sphere (although nothing suggests that money has become irrelevant to political attention given the continued importance of mass media).

The networked public sphere is not only more resistant to control by money, but it is also less susceptible to the lowest-common-denominator orientation that the pursuit of money often leads mass media to adopt.

To conclude, we need to consider the attractiveness of the networked public sphere not from the perspective of the mid-1990s utopianism, but from the perspective of how it compares to the actual media that have dominated the public sphere in all modern democracies.

There is, in this story, an enormous degree of contingency and factual specificity.